MyMenu1


Organizational Ecology

By: Clau González on 6/30/2014 at 4:26 PM Categories:
Organizational ecology theory has its roots in the natural selection work in biology. It is primarily concerned with the founding and death of organizations and organizational survival (Hannan & Freeman, 1977).

In addition, this theory focuses on organizational populations as the main unit of analysis. Therefore, research using an ecological perspective tends to look at sets of organizations over long periods of time.

The main components of this theory include inertia, age, and niche focus:
  • Inertia refers to the idea that organizations formed under similar circumstances have similar features, which are retained over their lifespan (Hannan & Freeman, 1977). 
  • Age concepts refer to the different pressures organizations face as they age. For instance, new organizations with new forms are more likely to fail (Stinchcombe, 1965). 
  • And the niche focus concept explores how either a specialist or a generalist focus impacts organizational survival (Carroll, 1985).

The key concepts in this theory include:
  • Variation, selection, retention, competition model (Darwinian vs. Lamarckian) 
  • Liability of newness (Stinchcombe 1965) 
  • Structural inertia (internal and external) (Meyer & Rowan 1977) 
  • Generalist vs. specialist (Meyer & Rowan 1977) 
  • Variability (degree of change) and grain (speed of change) 
  • Resource partitioning 
  • Niche overlap
  • Localized competition Isomorphism to the context

(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Resource Dependence

By: Clau González on 6/30/2014 at 4:11 PM Categories:
Resource Dependency Theory (RDT) acknowledges that every organization needs resources to function. These resources can be found both within and outside an organization. When the resources are outside the focal organization, it leads to interdependence and therefore uncertainty.

Thus the central ideas of RDT deal with power over resources, the strategies organizations employ to gain access and maintain power over those resources, and the social context where these decision take place (Scott & Davis, 2007). In order to reduce interdependence and uncertainty, organizations seek power over their key resources. In order to gain that power, they may employ many strategies including forming alliances, associations, an co-optation (Scott & Davis, 2007).

Organizations must exchange with other organizations for resources to survive, but the interdependence leads to power differences. Managers act to reduce such dependence while increasing its own power in relation to others (Pfeffer and Salancik 1978).

RDT rests on the following assumptions:

  • Organizations are comprised of internal and external alliances/coalitions created to influence or control.
  • The environment has scarce and valuable resources essential for the organization.
  • Organizations work to minimize dependence on other organizations and maximize other organization's dependence on them.

This theory can be applied at the organizational level by looking at power relationships among different organizations. It can also be applied at the unit level within an organization. Hillman, Withers and Collins (2009) have a useful review of how this theory has been used in management. They note that RDT has been tested in several corporate activities including mergers, vertical integration, joint ventures. They also note how this theory has applications in the study of inter-organizational relationships, board of directors, political action, and executive succession.

(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Contingency Theory

By: Clau González on 6/30/2014 at 3:24 PM Categories:
Contingency theory is primarily concerned with the idea that the organization should fit their internal organization to the environment.  This theory is focused on the individual organization and the choices made by the designers of the organization. In particular when it comes to the structure and scope that will yield the best outcomes. The concept of structure is defined as the level of formalization and centralization as well as the subunits created within the organization. The goal of the organization is to find the best fit between their chosen form and the environment. Ultimately, contingency theory does not prescribe one organizational form. Instead it argues that the best form is determined by the goodness of fit.

The logic of this theory is:
  1. Assume that everything depends on their environment (Woodward 1958, Lawrence & Lorsch 1967). 
  2. Given that there is no best way to organize and that any way of organizing is not equally effective (Galbraith 1973),
  3. Organizations whose structures were best adapted to the environment are expected to perform best (Pfeffer 1982).
This theory, then, has three concepts of interest. First, is the environment. This leads designers of the organizations to select a particular structure. This in turn leads to certain performance.

Diagram of the theory:

(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Sociological Foundations of Strategic Management

By: Clau González on 6/30/2014 at 2:21 PM Categories: |
Strategic management is, at its core, about how managers can transform environmental factors along with internal organizational resources to make decisions. These decisions should be based on goals and plans of action for reaching them.  The overarching goal is to guide the organization into the future in a dominant competitive position.

Given the importance of the environment in decision-making, sociology was a natural field for strategic management to draw on. The study of sociology centers around human social actions and social structure.

In 2004, W. Richard Scott published an article reviewing 50 years of organizational sociology. It this article, he detailed how the field has changed over time:

  • During the early 20th century, the study of organizational sociology came from the engineering orientation (Taylor 1911, Fayol 1919/1949).  
  • During the 1920s, the focus was on the historical view (Weber 1924/1968). 
  • By the 1930s, social scientists focused on unofficial, informal patterns of cooperation, shared norms and conflicts .
  • Then in the 1940s there was a shift in unit of analysis to organization (Barnard 1938, Selznick 1948). Researchers also looked at the paradox of manipulation and embeddedness. 
  • The 1950s brought the Carnegie-Mellon School of thought typified by bounded rationality (Simon), and the Columbia School, which focused on unintended consequences of purposive action (Merton).
  • The 1970s, researchers focused on perfect rationality vs. irrationality.
  • And the 1980s brought a higher level of anlaysis (organizational population, organizational fields, and networks).

Since strategic management requires the understanding of the environment, many theories used place a strong focus on it. Some of the most relevant are:
  • Contingency Theory: Galbraith 1973, Pfeffer 1982 
  • Resource Dependence Theory: Pfeffer & Salancik 1978 
  • Organizational Ecology: Stinchcombe 1965, Hannan & Freeman 1977 
  • Neo-institutional Theory: Meyer & Rowan 1977, DiMaggio & Powell 1983 
  • Networks: Granovetter 1985 
  • Social Movements: David, Morrill, Rao and Soule 2008 (Review) 
  • Organizational Identity: Dutton, Dukerich & Harguail 1994 
  • Categories and Classification: Zuckerman 1999, Hsu 2005

Economic Foundations Conclusion - Part 2

By: Clau González on 6/27/2014 at 2:02 PM Categories: |
This is the second part of the review of the Economic Foundations of Strategic Management. Part 1 here.

Transaction Cost Theory
  • Key idea:
    • There are costs associated with having operations inside the firm (hierarchy) or outside the firm (market).
  • Assumptions:
    • Self-interested behavior, bounded rationality.
    • Uncertainty and risks.
  • Unit of Analysis:
    • Transaction Costs.
  • Seminal papers and authors:
    • Coase (1937)
      • There are costs to use market transactions. 1) costs of discovering what the relevant prices are 2) negotiating and concluding a separate contract for each 3) difficulties of specifying all in a contract. By forming an organization and allowing some authority (entrepreneur) to direct resources, certain costs are saved. 
    • Alchain & Demsetz (1972)
      • They emphasize measurement problem in team production. They examined the difficulty of metering output in team production in which union or joint use of inputs yields a larger output than the sum of the products of the separately used inputs. They view a firm as a contractual structure arises as a means of efficiently organizing team production.
    • Klien, Crawford & Alchain (1978)
      • Contracts are open to serious risks. In the presence of appropriable quasi-rents, the possibility of post-contractual opportunistic behavior is real. This can be solved through vertical integration or contracts, with vertical integration being more likely.
    • Williamson (1985)
      • Unlike Alchain and Demsetz (1972), Williamson highlights the problem of opportunism in the context where executing transaction requires specific investments. According to him, transaction costs refers to negotiating, concluding and enforcement costs associated with transactions taking places in the market place. There are six main factors that produce transaction difficulties. 1) bounded rationality 2) opportunism 3) uncertainty and complexity 4) small number trading relationships 5) asset specificity 6) information impactedness. The joining of the different pairs of the factors generates particular transaction difficulties and they become serious especially when specific investments are required and information asymmetry between two parties is substantial. In theory, it is possible to use the market transaction if a comprehensive contingent claims contract is made; but in practice, it is almost impossible or prohibitively expensive to specify all the conditions, let alone monitoring such complicated contacts. 
    • Jones & Hill (1988)
      • Transaction costs should be incurred in order to use market transactions and they can be economized if the economic benefits of internalizing the transaction exceeds the bureaucratic costs of organizing transactions using a hierarchy. There are three ways to realize economic benefits from internalization. Economic benefits from vertical integration occurs when concerns about opportunism in small number trading relationships and information asymmetry between two parties is substantial. Economic benefits from related diversification are generated when inputs are shared or utilized in complete congestion. It is very difficult to realize such synergistic gains through market transactions due to transaction costs. Economic benefits from unrelated diversification have to do with the market failure as well as information asymmetry. Compared to external market investors who are at the disadvantage of information asymmetry and control disadvantage, the head office has overcome such weaknesses through its relationship with operating units. By acquiring a firm and exposing it to the discipline of efficient internal market competition, the head office, compared to external market investors, is at advantage of allocating resources more efficiently and thus increases performance. 
    • Teece (1982)
      • Diversification is driven by excessive capacity and its creation, market imperfection, and the peculiarities of organizational knowledge, particularly its fungibility and tacit nature.
    • Hill (1990)
      • Even when asset specificity is high, the problems of opportunism may be mitigated by systems of market in which selection favors actors with good reputation concerning trusting and cooperating relationship. However, transaction cost theory ignores a dynamic evolutionary process for such behavioral repertoire, and in this regard, their rationale for vertical integration may be overstated.
  • Similarity or relationship to other theories:
    • Agency theory makes similar assumptions to human behavior and human limits.
  • What kind of predictions can be made:
    • Make-or-buy decisions.
Resource-Based View
  • Key idea:
    • Sustained competitive advantage comes from idiosyncratic resources.
  • Assumptions
    • Tacit know-how resides in organizational routines.
  • Unit of Analysis:
    • Resources.
  • Seminal papers and authors:
    • Lippman & Rumelt (1982)
      • Uncertain imitability. This concept allows us to deal with causal ambiguity that exists when a link between resources controlled by a firm and its sustained competitive advantage is not understood perfectly.
    • Wernerfelt (1984)
      • He introduced the idea of analyzing the firm with a resource-product matrix instead of growth-share matrix. Also, diversification is discussed as a dynamic resource management. Acquisition is seen as a purchase of bundles of resources in a highly imperfect market.
    • Barney (1986a, 1986b)
      • For a firm’s resources to have sustained competitive advantages, they should have following attributes: 1) Valuable: resources should make the firm to exploit opportunities and/or neutralize threats in a competition. 2) Rare (path dependency assures this) among a firm’s competitors. 3) Inimitable (uncertain imitability Lippman and Rumelt 1992) -valuable and rare resources can be a source of sustained competitive advantage only when they are inimitable by competitors, and this is often true because a firm’s ability to acquire and exploit such resources depend on a firm’s unique historical conditions( place in time and space).
    • Conner (1991)
      • He argues that RBV provides an alternative rationale for the questions like why a firm exists and what determines a firm’s scale and scope. He maintains that heterogeneous firms continue to exist because the assets with which firms will come be mated are themselves heterogeneous, making each other a better fit than other firms. The theory views a firm as “a creator of unique productive value” instead of “an avoider of negative”. The scale and scope of a firm depends on a degree of to which new projects are specific to a firm’s current resource base. He also compares the RBV with other five traditional industrial organization economics. As the neoclassical view of the firm, RBV views a firm as an input-combiner but it does not include the assumptions of neoclassical views. Like the Bain-type IO, the RBV agrees that it is possible to make above-normal earnings but the profits come from idiosyncratic, immobile resources of a firm, not from the artificial reduction of industry outputs. As Schumpeter, the RBV recognizes the power of creative destruction (innovation) to shift market structure, but the RBV does not need large-scale industry incumbents for such initiative. Finally, like the Chicago school but unlike the Bain-type IO, the RBV sees such rents coming from luck or acumen of entrepreneurs in acquiring, combining and deploying such resources (conduct), not from the structure of the industry in which firms operate. 
    • Barney (1991)
      • Building on the assumptions that strategic resources are heterogeneously distributed across firms and that these differences are stable over time, this articles examines the link between firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Four empirical indicators of the potential of firm resources to generate sustained competitive – value, rareness, imitability, and substitutability – are discussed. 
    • Reed and DeFillippi (1990)
      • Argues that causal ambiguity is a function of tacitness, complexity, and specificity of competency
  • Similarity or relationship to other theories:
    • Dynamic capabilities - RBV looks at resources, DC looks at capabilities.
  • What kind of predictions can be made:
    • Impact of resources on firm performance, strategy.
Dynamic Capabilities
  • Key idea:
    • Sustained competitive advantage comes from capabilities.
  • Assumptions:
    • Competition as a process (Neo-Austrian economics).
  • Unit of Analysis:
    • Capabilities.
  • Seminal papers and authors:
    • Alchain (1950)
      • Like the biologists, the economist can predict the effects of environmental changes on the survival class of living organisms.
    • Schumpeter (1950)
      • The essential character of capitalism is its evolutionary process driven by a perennial gale of creative destruction
    • Nelson and Winter (1982)
      • Evolutionary relies on a cumulative learning-based view of organizational competence in the face of exogenous changes in the economic subsystem. Evolutionary theory explains how particular organizational forms come to exist in specific kinds of environments. The process is not necessarily efficient and path-dependent process can often lead to an outcome other than those implied by historical efficiency. Capabilities are captured in the organizational routines. Routines are the result of trial and error as organizational learn. Routines reflect the knowledge base of organizations. We can predict how organizations will behave in the future according to their routines, and even a high-level of complex problem solving efforts may fall into a quasi-routine pattern. 
    • Nelson & Winter (2002)
      • Building on the assumptions that strategic resources are heterogeneously distributed across firms and that these differences are stable over time, this articles examines the link between firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Four empirical indicators of the potential of firm resources to generate sustained competitive – value, rareness, imitability, and substitutability – are discussed. 
    • Teece et al (1997)
      • Dynamic capabilities framework (Efficiency-oriented): Stresses exploiting existing internal and external firm-specific competences to address changing environment. Conclusions: 1) Private wealth creation in regimes of rapid technological change depends in large measure on honing internal technological, organizational, and managerial processes. 2) Identifying new opportunities and organizing effectively and efficiently are more important than strategizing.
  • Similarity or relationship to other theories:
    • RBV looks at resources, DC looks at capabilities.
  • What kind of predictions can be made:
    • Impact of capabilities on firm performance, strategy.
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Economic Foundations Conclusion - Part 1

By: Clau González on 6/27/2014 at 11:41 AM Categories: |
This week, I spent my time reviewing theories used in strategic management that were derived from economics or grounded in economic concepts.

In one of my classes, we were encouraged to summarize theories by looking at the assumptions they make, how they are similar to other theories, the unit of analysis, and the predictions that can be made.

I will conclude the review of economic foundations by describing the major theories in those terms:

Industrial Organization
  • Key idea:
    • Builds on the theory of the firm. Looks at the impact of structure (read: boundaries) of firms and markets.
  • Assumptions:
    • Adds "complications" to perfectly competitive market.
  • Unit of Analysis:
    • Industry, firm.
  • Seminal papers and authors:
    • Stigler (1965)
      • Collusion is very difficult, even if firms want to do it.
    • Caves & Porter (1977) 
      • Entry barriers are both due to the structure, and also endogenous to the industry. Entry decisions to an industry depends on a firm's strategic position. 
    • Demstez (1973) 
      • Industries become concentrated due to their efficiency, not because of collusion.
    • Gilbert (1989) 
      • Industry structure is not strictly exogenous, but is endogenous as industry incumbents try to influence the behaviors of potential rivals by engaging in strategic entry deterrence behavior (either by forestalling entry or inducing exit).
    • Shapiro (1989)  
      • Overview of recent IO research that includes game theory; emphasizes the dynamics of strategic actions and the role of commitment in strategic settings, not possible to determine an overall theory of oligopoly.
    • Arthur (1989)  
      • Examine the dynamics of allocation under increasing returns in a context where agents choose between technologies competing for adoption.
  • Similarity or relationship to other theories:
    • Since it addresses boundaries of the firm, perhaps TCE can be a complement.
  • What kind of predictions can be made:
    • The structure of the industry can be used to create strategy for the firm.
Managerial Theories
  • Key idea:
    • There is a separation of ownership and control of the firm. Managers seek to maximize their own utility.
  • Assumptions:
    • Managers maximize their own utility.
  • Unit of Analysis:
    • Firm.
  • Seminal papers and authors:
    • Bearle & Means (1932)
      • Separation of ownership and control of the firm.
    • Marris (1963)
      • The optimal growth level requires the rate of diversification and profit margin but also a growth-maximizing financial policy. However, because a financial policy is under the hands of managers, an optimal growth level and optimal value of fiscal policy are often set from the point of view of managers, not of shareholders. 
    • Penrose (1965)
      • Some diversified growth represents efficient use of underutilized firm resources that cannot be separated out for sale. Expansion itself provides an opportunity to further growth, an opportunity that did not exist before the expansion, due to unused resources available at no extra cost. However, due to lack of managerial services (imagination, insight, creativity, experimenting etc), all potential opportunities known and open to a firm are not exploited together. 
    • Chandler (1985)
      • Vertical integration is driven by a desire to keep firms’ core assets to efficiently employed (assurance of supply) while diversification is the realization of economies of scope
  • Similarity or relationship to other theories:
    • Since it discusses the separation of ownership and control, agency theory.
  • What kind of predictions can be made:
    • Features of the firm (diversification or vertical integration) as a result of managers.
Agency Theory
  • Key idea
    • Because of separation of ownership and control, problems arise aligning priorities of managers with priorities of owners.
  • Assumptions
    • "Economic man."
  • Unit of Analysis
    • Principal-agent relationship.
  • Seminal papers and authors
    • Jensen & Meckling (1976)
      • Agency emerges as a response to managerial theory. 
    • Fama (1980)
      • Market for professional managers ‘disciplines’ managers to work for performance.
    • Demsetz (1983)
      • Corporate execs, while not often among the largest shareholders, receive incomes that are highly correlated with stock performance, and it forms a strong link between management and owner interests.
    • Fama & Jensen (1986)
      • Shows how organizations characterized by separation of ownership and control are so common and survive well despite of the agency problems. They show that such organizations control the agency problems by separating management (initiation and implementation) and control (reification and monitoring) of decisions. The common features of decision control system include mutual monitoring system, board of directors consisting of outsiders, decision hierarchies etc. 
    • Jensen (1986)
      • Debt reduces the agency costs of free cash flow by reducing the cash flow available for spending at the discretion of managers. Debt creation binds managers to keep their promise to pay the debts with future cash flow, in this sense it is an effective substitute of dividend.
  • Similarity or relationship to other theories:
    • Managerial theories of the firm. Agency theory came about as a direct response to that theory.
  • What kind of predictions can be made:
    • Behavior of managers based on different control tactics.
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Dynamic Capabilities

By: Clau González on 6/26/2014 at 9:54 AM Categories:
Like the Resource-Based View, dynamic capabilities theory emerged in the field of strategy.

This theory is grounded in Neo-Austrian or Schumpeterian Economics which views competition as a process (Alchain, 1950; Schumpeter, 1950; Nelson & Winter 1982).

It is similar the RBV of the firm in that it views competitive advantage as the result of valuable capabilities (resources) that are a result of an enterprise’s history. In this theory, capabilities emerge over time as a result of learning from trial and error. They are a path dependent product of a firm’s history.

The arguments in this theory are as follows:
  • Capabilities reside in the routines of an organization (Nelson & Winter, 1982) 
  • Routines capture the knowledge base of an organization. 
  • Routines have a substantial tacit dimension
  • Organizations remember by doing. 
  • Capabilities are not static; they evolve over time as a result of trial and error as enterprises learn – they are dynamic (Teece et al, 1997). 
Key articles on New-Austrian Economics and Dynamic Capabilities include:
  • Alchain (1950)
  • Schumpeter (1950)
  • Nelson and Winter (1982) 
  • Nelson & Winter (2002)
  • Chandler (1992)
  • Teece et al (1997)
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Resource-Based View

By: Clau González on 6/26/2014 at 9:36 AM Categories:
The resource-based view (RBV) theory emerged in the field of strategy, however it is firmly rooted in economic concepts.

It draws on Penrose’s (1955) theory of the firm, transaction cost analysis (Williamson, 1985), and the Neo-Austrian work of Nelson and Winter (1982).

One of the core assumptions is that firms are heterogeneous. This, it is argued, is a consequence of the path dependent accumulation of organizational knowhow over time (Nelson & Winter, 1982). Furthermore, it argues that sustained competitive advantage comes from idiosyncratic resources (factors of production) that are:
  • Owned by the enterprise 
  • Valuable 
  • Rare (path dependence assures this)
  • Inimitable (uncertain imitability – Lippman and Rumelt, 1982)
  • Non-substitutable
  • Non-tradable (due to transaction cost issues) 
In this framework, organizations come into possession of valuable and rare resources due to luck, entrepreneurial perception, accumulation of skill over time (organizational learning), or private information. In addition, tacit know-how is often depicted as a rare, valuable, non-tradable and inimitable resource.

This theory can be presented as a “complementary” perspective to tradition IO as exemplified by Porter (1980).

The biggest criticisms of this theory include:
  • It can be a tautology: resources are valuable because they are important to the organization; what makes a resource valuable? There is no independent criteria for this.
  • It can become a collection of "just right" stories
RBV articles include:
  • Lippman & Rumelt (1982)
  • Wernerfelt  (1984)
  • Barney (1986a, 1986b)
  • Conner (1991)
  • Barney (1991)
  • Reed and DeFillippi (1990)
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Transaction Costs

By: Clau González on 6/25/2014 at 4:33 PM Categories:
Transaction cost theory focuses on an organization's transactions. The central idea is that when organizations make decisions about their key operations, they either incur transaction costs or production costs. The transaction costs include costs and difficulties associated with the searching for the best supplier, as well as the creation implementation, and monitoring of a contract. Production costs, on the other hand, involve costs associated with the coordination of the people and processes inside a firm. The selection of one set of costs over the other is called the “make or buy” decision. Two factors associated with the choice to buy or make a key component of production is the level of uncertainty and the asset specificity. Both of these concepts are related to risk and the role it plays on a firm’s decisions.

This theory takes the transaction as the fundamental unit of analysis. This theory asks what determines if transactions are organized inside the firm (make, hirerchy) or outside the firm (buy, market). This is another way of thinking about the boundaries of an organization.

Seminal contributions have come from Alchain & Demsetz (1972), Coase (1937) and Williamson (1975, 1985). They hypothesize that there are costs associated with executing certain transaction via a market. Alchain & Demsetz, for instance, place an emphasis on measurement problems in cases of team production. Williamson emphasizes opportunism in contexts where undertaking exchange requires asset specific investments.

Transaction costs can be economized by internalizing the transaction within an organization, so long as the economic benefits of doing so exceed the bureaucratic costs of managing the transaction within a hierarchical setting (Jones & Hill, 1988).   Transaction cost theory assumes (as does agency theory) that in the long run, only firms that economize on transaction costs (or agency costs) will survive.

Product and capital markets perform a rough sort between the efficient and inefficient. This has implications for corporate strategy. A corporation may choose:
  • Diversification (Teece, 1980, 1982; Jones & Hill, 1988)
  • Vertical integration (Klien et al, 1978)
  • Foreign direct investment decisions (Hill & Kim 1988),
  • Quasi-integration (alliances – Hill, 1990).  
Several authors have attacked transaction costs and agency theory on grounds that:
  • They shape behavior and become self-fulfilling prophesies (Ghoshal & Moran, 1996)
  • They ignore the fact that economic transactions are embedded in social networks (Granovetter, 1985; Perrow, 1986), and that societal issues shape organization form.
  • They make unrealistic assumptions about selection mechanisms (Robins, 1987). 
  • They assume away the costs of internal hierarchy, and ignore the “fact” that a desire for market power drives much of corporate strategy (Perrow, 1986; Peffer & Salancik, 1978).
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Lego Calendar

By: Clau González on 6/25/2014 at 11:28 AM Categories:
I am having a hard time getting started today. So I decided to get warmed up by writing about how I like to stay organized. More specifically, how I organize my time.

The LEGO Calendar

lego calendar
Lego Calendar Awesomeness!

Why It's AWESOME

It is (in my own biased opinion) the best way to think about time. It is both visual and tangible. Each little block represents 30 minutes of time. As I plan my week, I can see and feel how much time I have and how much time I dedicate to each of my priorities. Nothing has made me realize the importance of prioritizing as holding a handful of legos in my hand. As I place a block on each day, I can literally feel the hours flying away.


How I Built It

Materials:
  • Lego Grey Baseplate
  • Lego Basic Bricks Deluxe Box
  • Specialty Pieces:
    • Flat Tile 2x4, Item: 87079, Qty. 1
    • Flat Tile 2x4, Item: 87079, Qty. 27
    • Flat Tile 1x2, Item: 3069, Qty.  6
    • Plate 1x2, Item: 3023, Qty.  6
    • Plate 2x4, Item: 3020, Qty. 1
    • Plate 2x4, Item: 3020, Qty. 27
Build it:
  1. Understand the layout
    I wanted to have seven columns. One for Labels, five for the days of the week, and one extra. I also wanted to have 10 hours of scheduling time per day. This meant that the first column had to be placed one stud from the edge. Here is an image with a clear map of the layout. Each label piece uses a plate and a flat piece. This makes the labels stand out more.

    You can choose to not purchase the plates and use the flat pieces only!
  2. Choose your colors and activities
    The Deluxe Box comes with nine colors. So make sure you choose your activities based on the number of pieces. For instance, there are more blue than brown pieces. Thus, I chose blue for my main activity (studying for comps as of this writing), and brown for my Yoga class. The red pieces go in the row labeled red, to indicate deadlines.
  3. Make the Labels
    I have a label maker, so I made a few labels with the days of the week, times, and names of my activities.

Use it:

Each day has two columns. The first one belongs to me and the second one to my officemate. The "other" column has the key to the meaning of the colors. Since we are both at different stages on the program, her days revolve around classes. We also included Lego figures of each of us, for funsies!

Naturally, most of my time is dedicated to comps. I have some admin time scheduled for research assistant tasks, and just an hour a day for my own research. I also have one long meeting scheduled each week. That is the time I dedicate to discussion of theories with my classmates.

I came about this distribution of tasks by thinking how much time of my day at the office I wanted (or needed) to spend on each activity. For example, if I am at the office 45 hours each week, I do not want more than five and a half hours per week spent on breaks. So I gathered enough black blocks and decided how that time would be distributed. Once those blocks were gone, there is no more time I can spend on that activity.

This calendar can also work for one person. The first column can represent the "ideal" day, and the second column can represent the "actual" day.


TL;DR
  • Legos allow you to see and feel how you spend your time - awesome!
  • Each block represents half an hour.
  • Think about your priorities and how much time you can/need to spend on them.
  • Assign the right number and color of blocks to each activity.
  • Build your calendar!

Have you built something similar? Please share!

Agency Theory

By: Clau González on 6/24/2014 at 12:27 PM Categories:
Agency Theory emerged as a response to managerial theory (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). The core idea is the relationship between stockholders (owners, principals) and managers (agents). This is often described as the principal-agent relationship. This theory assumes that managers (agents) may pursue goals that are not always aligned with those of their principles (stockholders). As a result, there is a loss in efficiency. In order to avoid misalignment of principal-agent interests, governance mechanisms have evolved to limit managerial discretions. These include:
  • Performance based compensation (stock options)
  • The board of directors (a monitoring mechanism)
  • Corporate debt
  • Market for corporate control (takeover constraint)
The costs to deal with the principal-agent problem are called agency costs.

Collectively, agency theory believes that incentive alignment, monitoring, and enforcement mechanisms are generally sufficient to limit managerial discretion. This has a couple of implications:
  • The scope for pursuing inefficient corporate strategies is limited. Management teams that do so will be replaced by teams that have the nest interests of owners in mind
  • Organizational forms (franchising, vertical integration) may be a response to agency costs.  
Some key articles include:
  • Jensen & Meckling (1976) 
  • Fama (1980)
  • Demsetz (1983)
  • Fama & Jensen (1986)
  • Jensen (1986)
  • Eisenhardt (1989)
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Managerial Theories

By: Clau González on 6/23/2014 at 4:19 PM Categories:
The managerial theories of firm growth are concerned with the role of management in the productivity and performance of the firm.

Some of the early work was conducted by Bearle & Means (1932). They discussed how in the modern corporation the control of the firm was no longer in the hands of the owners. Their argument revolved around managers having discretion over the goals and strategies of the enterprise. Most importantly, management does not have to maximize returns to owners.

A few of the main managerial theories come from Baumol (1968), Marris (1963), and Williamson (1964). They discuss how managers maximize a utility function that includes power, status, income, among other things. A large firm increases power, status, and income.
Therefore, management prefers growth maximizing rather than profit maximizing strategies. 

The managerial theories are often used to explain diversification, mergers and acquisitions. Furthermore, the emphasize how management often prioritizes maximizing the size of the empire.

This view has two implications.
  • Economic Welfare Implication:
    • Presumption against large diversified enterprises.
  • Strategy Implication
    • Much diversification may dissipate rather than create value.
    • For example, the presumption against unrelated or conglomerate diversification (Rumelt, (1974)).
This theory also has counterpoints. Most notably:
  • Penrose (1955): Diversified growth may represent the efficient use of under-utilized productive services (i.e. slack resources) that cannot be separated out for sale. 
  • Firms have limited rate of growth and size due to the  limited supply of managerial services.
  • Chandler (1962, 1977, 1985): Vertical integration was driven by a desire to keep core assets fully and efficiently employed (assurance of supply), while diversification was about the realization of economies of scope. 
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Industrial Organization Economics

By: Clau González on 6/20/2014 at 4:59 PM Categories:
The Economic Foundations of Strategy post set the stage to discuss more deeply how economics has shaped the study of strategy. Here, I will discuss Industrial Organization Economics (IO).

In broad terms, IO examines the structure of the firm and market. In order to do so, researchers typically use the Bain/Mason Structure-Conduct-Performance Paradigm. The main takeaway for this paradigm is that the industry structure leads to certain enterprise conduct which leads to performance. For example:
  • Structure: Industries became concentrated due to advantages of large firm size
    • Economies of Scale, Product Differentiation, Strategic Behavior
  • Conduct: In concentrated industries there was a tendency towards (tacit) collusion
    • Price wars were to be avoided (prisoners dilemma)
    • Price signaling, price leadership, emphasis on non-price competition
  • Performance: Collusive behavior led to maximization of joint returns.  
  • Implications: Underlay antitrust policy  

This paradigm was modified to look at how enterprise performance leads to industry structure which then leads to firm performance. Here the example is different:
  • Conduct: Firms pursue strategies to build entry barriers, forestall entry, or limit competition in other ways (Gilbert, 1989; Shapiro, 1989).
    • Limit pricing, product proliferation, credible investment commitments, strategic pre emption, etc.
    • Vertical Integration to control access to inputs or limit access to distribution
    • Diversification (cross-subsidization and multipoint competition)
  • Structure:  Some industries become concentrated due to network effects (Arthur, 1989)

The key question in IO is "what industry structure is in the best interests of society." This is clearly an an economic welfare question. Porter, however, changed the question to “what strategies are in the best interests of the firm." This second question clearly looks at the conduct and performance link within an industry.

Not all economists agreed with the Structure-Conduct-Performance paradigm. Some relevant critics include:
  • Demsetz (1973)
    • Industries become concentrated due to enterprise efficiency, not anti-competitive practices.
  • Stigler (1965)
    • Even if firms want to collude, information costs and enforcement issues make collusion very difficult if not impossible.
  • Schumpeter (1950)
    • Competition is a process driven by the “perennial gale of creative destruction.”
  • Christensen (1997)
    • The advantages of large scale can be and are nullified by innovation.
Some papers that have been mentioned above and that are relevant to IO include:
  • Caves & Porter (1977)
    • Entry barriers can apply in subgroup structures; entry decisions involve strategies of targeting groups and moving into specific segments over time.
  • Gilbert (1989)
    • Strategic behavior can exploit mobility barriers to the advantage of an established firm.
  • Shapiro (1989)
    • Overview of recent IO research that includes game theory; emphasizes the dynamics of strategic actions and the role of commitment in strategic settings, not possible to determine an overall theory of oligopoly.
  • Arthur (1989)
    • Examine the dynamics of allocation under increasing returns in a context where agents choose between technologies competing for adoption.
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Economic Foundations of Strategic Management

By: Clau González on 6/20/2014 at 10:36 AM Categories: |
Strategy draws on many disciplines. As discussed in the Strategy Background post, two of the main influences come from sociology and economics.

Today I will focus on the economic foundations of strategy. This post will be a broad overview of how economics has shaped the study of strategy. Additional posts will discuss theories in much more detail.

Economists, particularly those focused on industrial organization, had been studying issues that are relevant to strategy. For example, they looked at market structure, competitive behavior, vertical integration, diversification, and mergers and acquisitions.

Their research centered around the economic welfare of society. Most importantly, economists had a large body of theory, methodology, and evidence that could be used to address strategy questions.

The leap from theorizing about the economy to the organization was not very difficult. Thus, people trained in economics began to enter this field.

Some of the theories in the field of economics had an immediate application to strategy:

  • Industrial Organization Economics
  • Managerial Theories of the Growth of the Firm
  • Agency Theory
  • Transaction Cost Theory
  • Neo-Austrian Theories

Furthermore, some theories that have emerged in the field of strategy draw very heavily on economics:

  • Resource Based View of the Firm
  • Dynamic Capabilities
  • Knowledge Based Theories of the Enterprise
(Adapted from course notes)
(Flashcards and other resources here)

Strategic Management Background

By: Clau González on 6/19/2014 at 3:38 PM Categories:
Strategy as a field is relatively new.

It emerged during the 1970s and the early 1980s out of a requirement to have a business policy capstone class. One of the key indicators of the legitimacy of an area of study as a field are specialty journals. One of the first strategy-focused journals, Strategic Management Journal, started in 1981.

Early in the field, the focus was on two core ideas: strategy content and strategy process.

Strategy Process
This research drew on sociology, social psychology, and cognitive psychology. Scholars were focused on questions such as:
  • How are strategies chosen?
    • See Andrews (1971), Bower (1970), Mintzberg (1978), Burgleman (1983)
  • How do decision making biases factor into this process?  
    • See Tversky and Kahneman (1974), Schwenk (1984), Mason, (1969)

Strategy Content
This research drew on economics concepts. Scholars were interested in asking:
  • What is the best strategy to pursue?
    • At the industry level: Porter (1980)
    • At the corporate level: Chandler (1966), Rumelt (1974), Montgomery, (1981)
From this brief overview, it is possible to see that both sociology and economics are used in strategy research. Future posts will describe in more detail the economic and sociological foundations of strategy.